vol. 56, no. 3 (January), 1990,
pp. 832-34
The Theory of Free Banking: Money Supply under Competitive
Note Issue
by George A. Selgin
Totowa, NJ: Roman and Littlefield, 1988, pp. xiv, 218
During the monetary expansion of the 1970s, F. A. Hayek [1] made the
suggestion�he later described it as a "bitter joke"�that allowing the market
to provide a "choice in currency" may be the only way to stop inflation.
Joke or no joke, both Hayek [2] and notable others have since addressed
themselves to the economics of competitive note issue. Prominent among
the notable others are Lawrence H. White [3], who examined the experience
with and debate about free banking in early nineteenth-century Britain,
and now George A. Selgin, who has developed the ideas of Hayek and White
into a comprehensive theory of free banking.
Selgin has produced a bitter-sweet
analysis of actual and potential banking institutions in their capacities
for achieving and maintaining monetary equilibrium. Bitter, because it
demonstrates in the most fundamental way the futility of maintaining monetary
equilibrium through central direction. Neither a simple monetary rule religiously
observed by the central bank nor a well intentioned discretionary policy
implemented by an enlightened monetary authority is capable of making the
appropriate adjustments in the money supply. Sweet, because it demonstrates
that the monetary equilibrium which remains outside the reach of any central
bank is the unintended consequence of competitive note issue. The market
forces that govern the issue and retirement of private bank notes in response
to changing market conditions are spelled out in sufficient detail so as
to make free banking seem institutionally viable�if only the political
obstacles (not discussed by Selgin) could be overcome.
Economists who generally
rate market forces above central direction have long been willing to endorse
as an exception a centrally managed medium of exchange. Until recently,
competition among note-issuing banks has been considered only to show why
monopolization is necessary. If the bank notes issued by a multiplicity
of competing banks are wholly generic, then each bank stands to gain by
expanding its note issue even though the collective effect is unbounded
inflation. If, alternatively, the notes are treated as bank-specific liabilities,
then each bank's notes are bartered against the notes of each competing
bank in a market process that fails to yield a commonly accepted medium
of exchange. Selgin directs attention away from these two polar cases in
his discussion of note-brand discrimination (pp. 42-47). He identifies
a broad middle ground in which (1) a multiplicity of notes are readily
accepted as a means of payment, but (2) some note-brand discrimination
affects their acceptability as a store of value. By distinguishing between
money to spend and money to hold, Selgin is able to show how competing
banks can provide both viable money and monetary stability.
But Selgin does more than
provide a fresh hearing for free banking. By framing monetary questions
in the broadest context, he contributes importantly toward the integration
of price theory and monetary theory. Drawing on Hayek, Selgin portrays
the price system as an efficient means of disseminating information about
changing preferences and resource availabilities and as a rational basis
for evaluating entrepreneurial decisions (pp. 89-94). Then, with no loss
of continuity, he applies these Hayekian insights to the supply of money
under conditions of competitive note issue. Guided by changing demands,
where the changes may favor money over other assets or currency over checkable
deposits, individual banks take actions whose collective effect is a continuous
adjustment of the money supply (both quantity and
currency/deposit mix) to money demand.
The problems encountered
by a central bank attempting to replicate these money-supply adjustments
are shown to be fully analogous to those encountered by a central-planning
agent attempting to adjust resource usage in response to changing demands
for goods and services [p. 103 and passim]. Evaluating money-management
policies in the same way that we evaluate resource-management policies
enhances our understanding of such problems. Identifying problems faced
by, say, an energy czar requires that we understand how the energy market
would function in his absence. Similarly, identifying problems faced by
the Federal Reserve Chairman requires that we understand free banking.
Hence, The Theory of Free Banking has value wholly independent of
prospects for banking reform.
The macroeconomics that
underlies Selgin's analysis of free banking is at odds with conventional
views about monetary stability. The conventional judgment, for instance,
that monetary stability requires an unchanging price-level is called into
question (pp. 97-103). Typically, the goal of price-level constancy is
justified by reference to a long monetary tradition or defended with analogies
between the dollar as a measure of value and the pound, foot, and bushel
as measures of weight, length, and volume. Constancy is held to be the
sine
qua non of the physical measures�and likewise of the measure of value.
Selgin rejects the analogy
and argues instead in terms of money as a medium of exchange which facilitates
the coordination of economic activity. Building on the ideas of Haberler,
Hayek, Machlup and others, Selgin defines a monetary equilibrium in which
money-supply adjustments keep constant the product of the money supply
and its velocity of circulation. Any increase in the demand for money requires
an equivalent increase in supply. But with MV�and hence PQ�held
constant, growth in real output is to be accommodated not by monetary growth
but by downward price adjustments. Monetary equilibrium so-conceived is
defended as being the most conducive to economic coordination (despite
the changing value of money) and is argued to be the outcome of free banking.
There are some perplexities
in Selgin's book. His account of the evolution of free banking in the imaginary
society of Ruritania, for example, involves a ghost-of-gold that may be
more haunting than Selgin realizes. Following Menger, Selgin accounts for
the transformation of gold from its purely non-monetary to its dominantly
monetary character. But then, with the maturing of the free-banking system,
the demand for monetary gold fades away leaving the value of money to be
governed by gold's non-monetary uses [p. 31]. It is not clear, however,
that characteristics associated with a more conventionally conceived gold
standard can be associated with the gold standard in Ruritania.
Selgin avoids dealing with
this issue in later chapters by shifting the analysis from a gold-based
to a fiat-based free-banking system. Questions about the role of gold in
a free-banking system, however, do not detract significantly from the central
message of Selgin's book. Instead, these and many other points to ponder
suggest that the economics of free banking has a growing research agenda.
Roger W. Garrison
Auburn University
References
1. Hayek, Friedrich A. Choice in Currency: A Way to
Stop Inflation. London: Institute for Economic Affairs, 1976.
2. __________. Denationalization of Money, Second
(Extended) Edition. London: Institute for Economic Affairs, 1978 [first
ed., 1976].
3. White, Lawrence H. Free Banking in Britain: Theory,
Experience, and Debate, 1800-1845. New York: Cambridge University Press,
1984.
|