A Specific Factor Model of FTAA and North Carolina Textile and
Apparel Industries
Mostafa Malki
University of Texas - Brownsville
Henry Thompson
Auburn University
Osei-Agyeman Yeboah
North Carolina A&T State University
Textile and apparel industries in the US face import competition that
promises to increase under the Free Trade Area of the Americas.� The present paper utilizes a specific factors
model of production and trade to predict the potential impact of FTAA on the textile and
apparel industries in North Carolina.� Income
is redistributed across six labor skill groups in North Carolina, and returns
to capital in textiles and apparel fall as does output.��� In spite of falling prices for textiles and
apparels, the model predicts higher wages based on rising prices of other
products. �
��������� The Free Trade Area of the Americas
(FTAA) is a pending free trade agreement to include all of the Americas patterned
after the North America Free Trade
Agreement (NAFTA).� Smaller US apparel
producers have fought a losing battle of import competition in NAFTA and larger
US textile manufacturers have expanded into Mexico given the rules of origin
and yarn forward requirements.� US
textile export revenue from Mexico more than tripled between 1994 and 1999 with
apparels then re-exported to the US.� More
recently, US textile exports to Canada and Mexico are falling off and apparel
imports from China and the Caribbean Basin are increasing.
��������� The
FTAA will change
patterns of trade in various textile and apparel products.� South America has major cotton growing
regions, relatively cheap labor, and growing demand.� FTAA will raise average incomes throughout
the hemisphere but import competing industries will lose as resources shift
toward export production.� Income will be
redistributed between labor groups, capital, and other inputs.� Import competition will intensify for various US textile and apparel products but
export demand will expand for other products.�
��������� The textile and
apparel industries are key components of the North Carolina economy, the
largest textile state in the US and the fourth largest apparel state with 33%
and 8% of US employment in those industries. �In 1995 North Carolina had over 2,000 plants
employing about 250,000 but within a decade the number of plants declined by almost
40% and employment by 61%. �
The present paper projects
adjustments in North Carolina to FTAA in a general equilibrium model of
production of the state economy that focuses on the textile and apparel
industries.� The model assumes six labor
skill groups along with energy and industry specific capital inputs, generating
general equilibrium comparative static adjustments in outputs and factor prices
to projected product price changes due to FTAA.�
Outputs
also adjust to changing output prices in the general equilibrium.� The specific factors model is typically
applied to national economies but the present study applies it to a state
economy.�
The effects of changing prices of traded products on
factor prices depend on factor intensity and substitution. �The paper examines sensitivity of comparative
static results to various degrees of constant elasticity substitution. ��
��������� The comparative static model of competitive
production and trade developed for instance by Jones and Scheinkman (1977) and
Chang (1979) is part of the foundation of trade theory.� The model assumes constant returns, full
employment, and competitive pricing.� Each
industry in the state is assumed to have its own specific capital input in the
present specific factors model with perfect mobility of labor and energy input across
industries.�
��������� Full
employment is stated Ax= v where A is the matrix of cost minimizing unit
inputs, x is the output vector, and v is the input vector.� Competitive pricing in each industry is
stated ATw = p where w is a vector of factor prices and p a vector of product prices.� The state economy is assumed to be a price
taker in product markets.
��������� Full
employment leads to the first equation in (1) and competitive pricing to the
second.� Aggregate substitution terms sih summarize substitution of factor i when the price of factor h
changes.� Letting �� represent percentage change, the
model in elasticity form is
������������������ s������ l������ w����
� ���v�
��������������������������������������� ����������������= ������������������������������������������������������������������������������������ (1)
������������������ qT����� 0������� x������� �� p����������������������� ��������� ������������������ ������������������
where l is the matrix of industry shares, q �the matrix of factor shares s the matrix of substitution
elasticities.� Factor prices w and outputs x are endogenous in the model while factor endowments v and prices p are exogenous.� In the
small open state economy, exogenous prices change due to import competition and
export expansion under FTAA.
��������� Factor shares q�
are the portions of industry revenue paid to productive factors and industry
shares l the portions of factors employed by
industry, derived as in Thompson (1996).�
The present model is based on labor data for five skilled groups (managers,
professionals, service, agriculture, production) across manufacturing
industries, services, and agriculture from the BLS (Bureau of Labor Statistics,
2000).� Energy spending by industry is
from the US Department of Energy (1998).�
Value added for agriculture is from the ERS/USDA (1999) and for
manufacturing from the US Census of Manufacturers (1997).� Value added in services is the residual of
state output.� Capital receives the
residual of value added after the labor and energy bills.� Due to the lack of data for energy input in the
service sector, the model uses 2% which is the smallest energy factor share in
manufacturing.�
��������� The
value of factor i input in industry j is wij � wivij where wi is the price of factor i and vij the quantity of factor i
used in industry j.� The share
of factor i in industry j is then qij � wij/yj where yj is the value added of industry j.� Factor index i runs across industry
capital k, energy e,
and the five skilled types of labor.� The
six industries are
G ����� agriculture� ���������������������������� S ������ services
T ����� textile mills����������������������������� P
����� textile products�������������
A ����� apparel manufacturing����������� M����� other manufacturing
and
the inputs are
������������������ Lm����� managers��� ���������������������������� Lp����� professional labor
������������������ Ls����� service labor������������������������������������� Lc����� clerical labor
������������������ La����� agricultural labor�������������������� Lw����� production labor
������������������ Kj����� industry specific capital��������� E������ energy.
��������� Table
1 is the total factor payment matrix.� Agricultural
workers are industry specific, service workers almost so, and about � of
production workers are in other manufacturing M.� North Carolina manufacturing
accounts for about � of value added, high relative to the US. �Textile mills are just over 11% as large as the
rest of manufacturing, apparel about half as large as textile mills, and
textile products less than half as large as apparel.� Textile and apparel industries sum to about
9% of state value added.
Table 1. �Factor payments ($mil)
|
G
|
S |
M |
T |
P |
A |
income
|
Lm
|
43 |
20,264 |
2,805 |
248 |
37 |
148 |
23,544 |
Lp |
89 |
32,995 |
2,187 |
55 |
12 |
67 |
35,406 |
Ls |
84 |
28,974 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
29,058 |
Lc |
0 |
13,972 |
136 |
110 |
15 |
27 |
14,261 |
La |
200 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
200 |
Lw |
467 |
0 |
11,552 |
2,346 |
425 |
1,103 |
15,892 |
ΣjKj |
3,080 |
23,201 |
110,610 |
14,434 |
2,245 |
5,843 |
159,414 |
E |
1,094 |
28,754 |
6930 |
171 |
35 |
47 |
37,032 |
value added |
5,057 |
148,162 |
134,220 |
17,365 |
2,769 |
7,235 |
314,807 |
Summing a column in Table 1 gives
total industry revenue.� The total
revenue of services in Table 1 is $148 billion making the capital share
$23.2/$148 = 15.7%.� Table 2 presents the
derived factor shares.� Capital has the
largest factor share except in services, and the largest factor shares in the textile
and apparel industries are for production workers.�
Table� 2.�
Factor shares qij
|
G
|
S |
M |
T |
P |
A |
Lm
|
.008 |
.137 |
.021 |
.014 |
.013 |
.020 |
Lp |
.018 |
.223 |
.016 |
.003 |
.004 |
.009 |
Ls |
.017 |
.196 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
Lc |
0 |
.094 |
.001 |
.006 |
.005 |
.004 |
La |
.040 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
Lw |
.092 |
0 |
.086 |
.135 |
.154 |
.152 |
Kj |
.609 |
.157 |
.824 |
.831 |
.811 |
.808 |
E |
.216 |
.194 |
.052 |
.010 |
.013 |
.006 |
���������
Industry shares in Table 3 show the distribution of inputs
across industries.� The sum across rows
in Table 1 gives total factor income.� Perfect
labor mobility within the state implies the wage of each type of labor is the
same across industries, and industry shares can be derived.� For instance, total income of service workers
is $29 billion implying $28.9/$29 = 99.7% of service workers are in the service
sector. �Professionals and managers also typically
work in services.� Very large shares of
service workers and clerks are in the large service sector, and production
workers in manufacturing.� Capital
industry shares equal one since capital is industry specific.�
Table 3.� Industry shares
lij
|
G
|
S |
M |
T |
P |
A |
Lm
|
.002 |
.861 |
.119 |
.011 |
.002 |
.006 |
Lp |
.003 |
.932 |
.062 |
.002 |
0 |
.002 |
Ls |
.003 |
.997 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
Lc |
0 |
.980 |
.010 |
.008 |
.001 |
.002 |
La |
1.00 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
Lw |
.029 |
0 |
.727 |
.148 |
.027 |
.069 |
E |
.030 |
.776 |
.194 |
.187 |
.005 |
.001 |
The assumption of perfect mobility of
each type of labor is based on the notion that clerks, for instance, could move
between industries finding in response to wage differentials.� Labor mobility is certainly not perfect.� Changing industries may involve moving and
workers must consider local amenities in making their job location
decision.� Assuming a fixed endowment of
each type of labor does not allow workers to switch between classifications but
in reality there would be at least some mobility of workers across labor
types.� These issues go well beyond the
present competitive model but might not greatly influence the comparative
static analysis and conclusions of the simulations.
Textile and apparel industries employ
about a quarter of production workers, and textile mills alone employ about
15%.� Apparel manufacturing employs about
half as many production workers as textile mills, and textile products half of
that.� The intensity and high employment
of production workers in textiles suggests there will be a large effect of FTAA
on the demand for production workers.
3.� Comparative Static
Elasticities in the Applied Specific Factors Model
��������� Substitution elasticities summarize adjustment in cost minimizing
inputs when factor prices change as summarized by Jones (1965) and Takayama (1982).� Following Allen (1938) the cross price
elasticity Sihj between the input of factor i and the
payment to factor h in industry j is derived from the Allen elasticity Eihj
as Sihj = qhjEihj.� Linear homogeneity implies �kEikj
= 0 and the own price elasticities Eiij
are derived the negative sum of the cross price elasticities.� Cobb-Douglas production implies unit Allen
elasticities Eihj implying substitution
elasticities equal factor shares, Sihj = qhj.� Constant elasticity of
substitution (CES) production implies the Allen partial elasticity has some
positive value.� The present simulations
apply a range of CES substitution for sensitivity.�
��������� Substitution
elasticities are the weighted average of industry cross price elasticities, sih � �jlijEihj
= �jlijqhjSihj.� Factor shares and industry
shares are sufficient to derive CES substitution elasticities.� Table 4 reports Cobb-Douglas substitution elasticities,
and CES scales these elasticities accordingly.�
For instance, if CES = � the substitution elasticities would be half as
large.� Substitution elasticities in the
applied production literature range from � to 1.� Notation in Table 4 includes Li
for labor inputs and K for industry capital.� Energy input is E and e its
price.� Industry capital returns are rj.
�������������������������� ��������������������������������������
|
wm |
wp |
ws |
wc |
wa |
ww |
e |
rG |
rS |
rM |
rT |
rP |
rA |
Lm |
-1.46 |
.194 |
.168 |
.081 |
0 |
.013 |
.249 |
.001 |
.726 |
.021 |
.002 |
0 |
.001 |
Lp |
.129 |
-1.41 |
.182 |
.088 |
0 |
.006 |
.201 |
.001 |
.786 |
.011 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
Ls |
.136 |
.222 |
-1.45 |
.094 |
0 |
0 |
.158 |
.001 |
.841 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
Lc |
.134 |
.218 |
.192 |
-1.55 |
0 |
.002 |
.170 |
0 |
.826 |
.002 |
.001 |
0 |
0 |
La |
.008 |
.018 |
.017 |
0 |
-1.14 |
.092 |
.609 |
.391 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
Lw |
.019 |
.014 |
0 |
.002 |
.001 |
-1.04 |
.817 |
.011 |
0 |
.128 |
.025 |
.005 |
.013 |
E |
.110 |
.177 |
.152 |
.073 |
.001 |
.020 |
-1.23 |
.012 |
.655 |
.033 |
.001 |
0 |
0 |
KG |
.008 |
.018 |
.017 |
0 |
.040 |
.092 |
.216 |
-.391 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
KS |
.137 |
.223 |
.196 |
.094 |
0 |
0 |
.194 |
0 |
-.843 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
KM |
.021 |
.016 |
0 |
.001 |
0 |
.086 |
.052 |
0 |
0 |
-.176 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
KT |
.014 |
.003 |
0 |
.006 |
0 |
.135 |
.010 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
-.169 |
0 |
0 |
KP |
.013 |
.004 |
0 |
.005 |
0 |
.154 |
.013 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
-.189 |
0 |
KA |
.020 |
.009 |
0 |
.004 |
0 |
.152 |
.006 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
-.192 |
���������
��������� The largest own substitution occurs
for clerk wages with every 1% increase leading to over a 1.5% decrease in their
input.� The smallest own substitution is
for capital in textile mills where every 1% increase decreases input by
0.17%.� Own elasticities are inelastic
for capital but elastic for labor.� There
is weak cross price substitution.
��������� Table 5 reports
the elasticities of factor prices with respect to product prices.� These comparative static elasticities
are found by inverting the system matrix in (8).� Some
factors benefit but others lose, and the effects are uneven.
|
pG |
pS |
pM |
pT |
pP |
pA |
wm |
-.002 |
.983 |
.016 |
.001 |
0 |
.001 |
wp |
-.002 |
1.01 |
-.001 |
-.001 |
0 |
0 |
ws |
-.003 |
1.02 |
-.019 |
-.001 |
0 |
-.001 |
wc |
-.005 |
1.02 |
-.016 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
wa |
1.05 |
-.012 |
-.024 |
-.005 |
-.001 |
-.003 |
ww |
.038 |
.587 |
.282 |
.052 |
.011 |
.029 |
e |
.012 |
.952 |
.031 |
.002 |
.001 |
.001 |
rG |
1.56 |
-.497 |
-.052 |
-.008 |
-.002 |
-.005 |
rS |
-.004 |
1.03 |
-.018 |
-.001 |
0 |
-.001 |
rM |
-.005 |
-.167 |
1.18 |
-.006 |
-.001 |
-.003 |
rT |
-.006 |
-.135 |
-.046 |
1.19 |
-.002 |
-.005 |
rP |
-.007 |
-.155 |
-.054 |
-.010 |
1.23 |
-.005 |
rA |
-.007 |
-.160 |
-.054 |
-.010 |
-.002 |
1.23 |
��������� Every 1% increase in the
price of agriculture would raise agricultural wages by 1.05%, production wages by
0.38%, and the return to capital in agriculture by 1.56%.� Higher agricultural prices increase
agricultural output and attract labor from other industries raising its capital
productivity.� Every 1% increase in the
price of other manufactures would raise production wages by 0.28%, wages of managers
by 0.02%, and capital returns by 1.18%.�
��������� Wages depend very little
on prices of textiles and apparel, but heavily on the price of services.� Only capital owners in the industry have much
at stake with changing textile and apparel prices.� Even production workers would suffer less
than half of 1% decline in wages with a 10% price decline for textiles and
apparel.� The reasons for the small
effect are increased outputs in other industries and labor mobility across
industries.�
��������� If labor were industry
specific the effect of falling prices would be lower wages with effects on the
scale of capital returns.� Given labor
contracts with fixed wages, the effect would switch to increased
unemployment.� Certainly these issues are
locally important but the effects would be transitory.� The present assumption of labor mobility
captures inevitable competitive forces.
��������� Thompson and Toledo
(2001) show the comparative static effect of price changes on factor prices are
the same for any CES production function.�
The degree of substitution, constant along isoquants, does not affect these
general equilibrium price elasticities in competitive models of
production.� The comparative static
elasticities in Table 5 then apply with any degree of CES substitution.
��������� Table 6 reports price
elasticities of outputs along the production frontier.� A higher price raises its output drawing labor
and energy away from other industries.�
The largest own output effect occurs in agriculture where a 10% price
increase raises output 5.64%.� Every 1%
price increase in textile and apparel raises its output about 0.2%.� The smallest own effect is for services
because there are fewer resources to attract from the rest of the North
Carolina economy.
|
pG |
pS |
pM |
pT |
pP |
pA |
xG |
.564 |
-.497 |
-.052 |
-.008 |
-.002 |
-.005 |
xS |
-.004 |
.025 |
-.018 |
-.001 |
0 |
-.001 |
xM |
-.005 |
-.167 |
.182 |
-.006 |
-.001 |
-.003 |
xT |
-.006 |
-.135 |
-.046 |
.194 |
-.002 |
-.005 |
xP |
-.007 |
-.155 |
-.054 |
-.010 |
.231 |
-.005 |
xA |
-.007 |
-.160 |
-.054 |
-.010 |
-.002 |
.233 |
4.� Adjustments to FTAA
��������� NAFTA has had a negative
impact on US textile and apparel industries.�
Predictions across industries varied according to factor intensity with
labor intensive industries projected to decline as in Weintraub, Rubio, and
Jones (1991), Marchant and Rupel (1993), Boyd, Krutilla, and Kinney (1993),
Hansen (1994), Thompson (1996), ERS/USDA (1998a), and Wall (2000).�
��������� The present assumptions regarding
FTAA price changes are that the price of textiles and apparel will fall along
with the average price of agricultural products.� The price of other manufactures is assumed to
stay constant while the price of services rises.� To derive the endogenous vector of factor price adjustments,
multiply a vector of predicted price changes by the matrix of factor price
elasticities in Table 5.�
Table 7 assumes a range of FTAA price changes
in the FTAA Prices columns for some
perspective on potential adjustments.�
While the price changes are arbitrary, results scale to the level of
price changes and the factor price adjustments in the second set of columns are
identical for any degree of CES.�
Table 7.� Factor price and output adjustments to FTAA
Prices
|
% FTAA
Prices |
|
% Factor prices |
|
% Outputs |
% Long
run outputs |
||||||
pG
|
0����
-2 ����-5 |
rG |
.15 |
-3.2 |
-8.0 |
xG |
.15 |
-1.2 |
-3.0 |
.15 |
-3.2 |
-8.0 |
S |
0������ 1 �����2 |
rS |
.03 |
1.1 |
2.3 |
xS |
.03 |
0.1 |
0.2 |
.03 |
1.1 |
2.3 |
pM |
-1 �����-2���
-5 |
rM |
-1.1 |
-2.3 |
-5.9 |
xM |
-.12 |
-.29 |
-.86 |
-1.1 |
-2.3 |
-5.9 |
pT |
-5��
��-20 ��-30 |
rT |
-5.8 |
-24 |
-35 |
xT |
-.86 |
-3.7 |
-5.5 |
-5.8 |
-24.0 |
-35 |
pP |
-5 ����-20
��-30 |
rP |
-6.0 |
-24 |
-36 |
xP |
-1.0 |
-4.3 |
-6.4 |
-6.0 |
-24 |
-36 |
pA |
-10 ���-30 ��-50 |
rA |
-12 |
-37 |
-61 |
xA |
-2.2 |
-6.8 |
-11 |
-12 |
-36 |
-61 |
|
wm |
-.03 |
.91 |
1.8 |
|
|||||||
wp |
.01 |
1.0 |
2.1 |
|||||||||
ws |
.03 |
1.1 |
2.2 |
|||||||||
wg |
.02 |
1.1 |
2.2 |
|||||||||
wa |
.08 |
-1.9 |
-4.8 |
|||||||||
ww |
-.89 |
-2.2 |
-3.8 |
|||||||||
e |
-.06 |
.78 |
1.6 |
Wage adjustments are generally very small due
to the mobility of labor across industries, and are linked to factor and
industry shares.� Only when prices change
in the range of 20% and upward are there noticeable wage effects.� Capital returns, however, adjust to a larger
extent than their price changes due to the magnification effect.� Adjustments in the price of energy e are negligible.�
��������� Output
adjustments in Table 7 are found by multiplying output elasticities in Table 6
by the vectors of projected price changes.�
Output adjustments are much less than price changes in the short.� Output adjustments scale with CES substitution and
would be half as large with CES = � and estimates of substitution in the
literature generally fall in the range of � to 1.� Changes in outputs also scale to their price
changes.�
��������� It is reasonable to
assume the price of textile mill products would rise but apparel prices would fall
under FTAA.� Output and capital returns generally
follow price changes.� The present model
suggests output adjustments would be smaller but capital return adjustments
larger than industrial price changes.��
��������� A
decreased capital return will lower investment and generate larger long run
output adjustments.� To examine the long
run potential output adjustment, assume the elasticity of capital with respect
to its return equals one as is approximately the case under the present model. �In the production adjustment, the percentage change
in industry output would then be about equal to the percentage change in its
capital stock.� These capital stock
changes magnify output adjustments in the long run.� The last column of Table 7 shows these long
run output changes and the declines in textile and apparel outputs are
sizeable.�
��������� Factor price changes are proportional to the vector of price
changes.� For instance, a doubling of price
changes in a particular vector leads to factor price and output adjustments twice
as large as those in Table 7.
��������� Results are insensitive to
the assumption of specific capital.� The
various types of labor are nearly specific to their particular industries:
managers, professionals, and service workers in services, agricultural workers
in agriculture, and production labor in other manufactures.� Price changes have similar effects on income
distribution regardless of whether capital is industry specific.�
5.�
Conclusion
The present applied specific factors model projects
the range of income redistribution and output changes in North Carolina as it adjusts
to FTAA.� The North Carolina textile and
apparel industry will suffer import competition under FTAA but there will be
rising prices and export opportunities for production intensive in skilled
labor.� �����
Output and wage adjustments will not be overwhelming
under reasonable price scenarios but adjustments in capital returns are
magnified effects of price changes.� Wage
adjustments are small due to the assumption of labor mobility across
industries, and would be magnified effects of price changes if labor were
immobile between industries.� Labor could
retrain in response to changing wages for particular skills and labor mobility
between skill groups would diminish the wage impacts.�
Output adjustments will be negligible in
services and other manufacturing.� Wages
of all but agricultural and production workers rise in FTAA while returns to
capital fall in the textile and apparel as well as other manufacturing
industries.� Output adjustments are
smaller than their price decreases in the short run but larger in the long run
due to declining investment, and textile and apparel output will substantially
fall in the long run.
References
Allen, R.G.D. (1938) Mathematical
Analysis for Economists. �MacMillan.
Boyd, R.G., K. Krutilla, and N.C. Kinney (1993) �The
Impact of Tariff Liberalization between the United States and Mexico: An
Empirical Analysis,� Applied Economics 22, 81-89.
Bureau of Labor Statistics (2000) web page.
Chang, Winston (1979) �Some Theorems of Trade and
General Equilibrium with Many Goods and Factors,� Econometrica 47,
709-726.
ERS/USDA
(1999) Farm Income and Costs: Farm Income
Forecasts.
ERS/USDA
(1998a) �Free Trade in the Americas,� International Agriculture and
Trade Reports, Situation and Outlook Series, WRS-98-1; 54.
ERS/USDA
(1998b) �Free Trade in the Americas: Potential Advantages for U.S.
Agriculture,� Agricultural Outlook, April: 11-15.
Hansen, N. (1994) �NAFTA: Implications for U.S.
Regions,� The Survey of Regional Literature, 4-22.
Jones, Ron (1965) �The Structure of Simple General
Equilibrium Models,� Journal of Political Economy, 557-572.
���������
Jones,
Ronald and Jos� Scheinkman (1977) �The Relevance of the Two-Sector Production
Model in Trade Theory,� The Journal of Political Economics 15, 65-99.
Marchant, M. A. and F.J.
Rupel (1993) �The Impacts of Lesser Developed Countries on Southern Region
Agricultural Exports,� Agricultural and Resource Economic Review 22,
71-87.
Takayama, Akira (1982) �On
the Theorems of General Competitive Equilibrium of Production and Trade � A
Survey of Some Recent Developments in the Theory of International Trade,� Kieo
Economic Studies, 1-37.
Thompson, Henry (1996) �NAFTA
and Industrial Adjustment: Specific Factor Model of Production in Alabama,� Growth
and Change, 3-28.
Thompson, Henry and Hugo
Toledo (2001) �Bolivia and South American Free Trade,� International Trade
Journal, 113-126.
US Census of Manufacturers (1997) Manufacturing
by Subsector.
US
Department of Energy (1998) Expenditures
for Purchased Energy Sources, 1998; National Data and Regional Totals.
Wall,
Howard (2000) �NAFTA and the Geography of North American Trade,� Federal
Reserve Bank of St Louis Working Paper, www.stls.frb.org/docs/research/wp/2000-017.pdf.
Weintraub,
S, .L. Rubio, and A. Jones (1991) US - Mexican Industrial Integration: The Road to
Free Trade, Boulder: Westview Press.
�
�
�